Donald Boudreaux: Difficult-to-see consequences of minimum wage | TribLIVE.com
Donald J. Boudreaux, Columnist

Donald Boudreaux: Difficult-to-see consequences of minimum wage

Donald J. Boudreaux
1875809_web1_gtr-cmns-Boudreaux-110119

Minimum-wage legislation artificially raises firms’ costs of employing low-skilled workers. In consequence, some workers who would have jobs in the absence of the minimum wage are cast by the minimum wage into the ranks of the unemployed.

This understanding was long the consensus among economists. Starting in the mid-1990s, however, some researchers found that raising the minimum wage does not necessarily have a negative impact on employment.

For a quarter-century, a battle royale has raged among economists over whether or not this new research is sufficiently solid to overturn the long-held consensus. Studies of minimum wages continue to pour forth. While a majority of recent studies support the consensus, enough studies dispute it to allow minimum-wage supporters to dismiss as false the traditional economic argument against the minimum wage.

My professional opinion is that the most credible studies are those that show higher minimum wages to be associated with reduced employment of low-skilled workers. But even if I’m mistaken, it’s important to understand that raising the minimum wage can negatively affect workers even if it doesn’t throw any of them out of jobs.

Even the simplest entry- level job — which is the sort that nearly all minimum-wage workers hold — is a complex bundle of benefits and requirements. On the benefits side, most obviously, is the wage itself — for example, $7.25 per hour, the current federally mandated minimum wage.

But there are benefits to most jobs beyond the wage. Some of these benefits we might call “formal” fringe benefits, such as employer- paid health insurance premiums. Also common are other, less formal fringe benefits. These include, for instance (and depending on the particular job), free meals, employer- supplied uniforms, employee discounts for workers at retail stores and generous opportunities for overtime work.

Looking even more closely, we see that the likes of comfortable break rooms, company picnics, Friday happy hours and employee-of-the-month recognition are also benefits that make jobs that offer these amenities better than those that don’t.

When government raises the minimum wage, employers can reduce the amount of nonwage benefits paid to employees. And so even workers who keep their jobs at the higher minimum wage might nevertheless be made worse off because of reductions in the value of their nonwage benefits.

A similar dynamic operates on the requirements side of jobs. Employers, obviously, expect their employees to produce enough to make their employment worthwhile for employers. And so if the minimum wage is raised, employers can work their employees harder.

Employers can become more strict in demanding that workers arrive on time and in punishing workers who leave work a few minutes early, or cracking down on personal texting, telephoning and emailing during work hours. This intensified strictness enables employers to get more output per hour from each worker.

In short, employers can respond to hikes in the minimum wage by employing fewer workers, cutting the value of workers’ fringe benefits or working employees harder. Most employers will use some combination of these three options. And to the extent that employers either cut the value of fringe benefits or work their employees harder, they will have less incentive to reduce the size of their workforce.

But make no mistake: Employers will adjust in one or more of these three ways — each of which makes workers worse off.

Donald Boudreaux is a professor of economics and Getchell Chair at George Mason University in Fairfax, Va. His column appears twice monthly.

TribLIVE commenting policy

You are solely responsible for your comments and by using TribLive.com you agree to our Terms of Service.

We moderate comments. Our goal is to provide substantive commentary for a general readership. By screening submissions, we provide a space where readers can share intelligent and informed commentary that enhances the quality of our news and information.

While most comments will be posted if they are on-topic and not abusive, moderating decisions are subjective. We will make them as carefully and consistently as we can. Because of the volume of reader comments, we cannot review individual moderation decisions with readers.

We value thoughtful comments representing a range of views that make their point quickly and politely. We make an effort to protect discussions from repeated comments either by the same reader or different readers

We follow the same standards for taste as the daily newspaper. A few things we won't tolerate: personal attacks, obscenity, vulgarity, profanity (including expletives and letters followed by dashes), commercial promotion, impersonations, incoherence, proselytizing and SHOUTING. Don't include URLs to Web sites.

We do not edit comments. They are either approved or deleted. We reserve the right to edit a comment that is quoted or excerpted in an article. In this case, we may fix spelling and punctuation.

We welcome strong opinions and criticism of our work, but we don't want comments to become bogged down with discussions of our policies and we will moderate accordingly.

We appreciate it when readers and people quoted in articles or blog posts point out errors of fact or emphasis and will investigate all assertions. But these suggestions should be sent via e-mail. To avoid distracting other readers, we won't publish comments that suggest a correction. Instead, corrections will be made in a blog post or in an article.